Photo of Ann Lipton

Ann M. Lipton is Tulane Law School's Michael M. Fleishman Professor in Business Law and Entrepreneurship and an affiliate of Tulane's Murphy Institute.  An experienced securities and corporate litigator who has handled class actions involving some of the world’s largest companies, she joined the Tulane Law faculty in 2015 after two years as a visiting assistant professor at Duke University School of Law.

As a scholar, Lipton explores corporate governance, the relationships between corporations and investors, and the role of corporations in society. Read More

Is a question I get asked a lot, especially after Musk offered an enthusiastic gesture that absolutely, positively, in no way resembled a Nazi salute pleasedon’tsueme. 

And the answer is – no. 

Even under the law of Delaware-before-SB-21 (and before Texas’s “hold my beer” alternative, which would among other things, prevent not only shareholders, but the corporation’s own board, unprompted, from suing a director or officer in the right of the corporation for anything other than fraud, intentional misconduct, ultra vires acts, or knowing violations of law), this cannot be the basis for a claim by Tesla’s shareholders against Elon Musk.

As Tesla’s CEO and a member of the board, Elon Musk owes Tesla a duty of care, and a duty of loyalty.  That means he cannot run Tesla with gross negligence – which, under Delaware law (let’s assume Texas law is no more strict), would be defined as akin to recklessness – and he cannot be disloyal, which means acting under a conflict of interest, intentionally trying to harm the company, or intentionally failing to take action to benefit Tesla when he knows he has a duty to take such action.

Let’s start with loyalty.  Whatever

Meredith Ervine at Deallawyers highlights this blog by Milbank on Advance Notice Bylaws. Two things stand out to me.

First, apparently companies are now requiring nominating activists to vote only their long positions, not borrowed shares:

While lending shares of the corporation to cover short sales may provide income for large fund complexes, it is unlikely that these fund complexes (or other long-term holders) wish to promote empty voting in a contested corporate election.  Permitting the voting of borrowed shares by an activist – amplifying the activist’s voting power when there is no meaningful economic stake in the shares being voted – misaligns voting power with the economic consequences of the vote and does not promote good long-term decision making. The Alignment ANB accordingly requires the nominating stockholder and allied participants in the solicitation to waive their right to vote shares in excess of their collective net long position – in other words, to waive the right to vote shares that were borrowed or otherwise subject to an offsetting sale or delivery obligation.

I didn’t know you could do that by bylaw! Do similar requirements apply to incumbents (a la Kiani at Masimo?).

Second, Milbank recommends questionnaires

There is always something new to discover.

For example, I was reviewing the CLC version (as one does), and I noticed that in the sections providing for stockholder approval (either for director-conflict transactions, or controller-conflict transactions), language was deleted that would specifically have required stockholders be informed as to the nature of a director’s conflict and involvement in the negotiation of the transaction, and the “material facts” of a controller transaction – though this language was retained for approval at the board/committee level. Though stockholder approval must still be “informed,” I rather suspect the deletions were intended to assist with future arguments that conflicts, or flawed “negotiations,” do not undermine the effect of a stockholder vote, when the stockholders were at least informed as to the material terms of the deal.

Screenshots of the relevant deletions, here:

And here:

This is, I believe, the language included in the version of the bill that passed the Delaware Senate.

In recent years, of course, the Delaware Supreme Court has rejected many attempts at stockholder ratification on the grounds that various conflicts or negotiating flaws were concealed from stockholders, and these were the grounds on which Chancellor McCormick concluded that the stockholder vote

Like this Walgreen’s deal with Sycamore.

Very quick thing I note about it: It includes the equivalent of an earnout, namely, in addition to the cash consideration Walgreen’s shareholders receive, they also receive a “Divested Asset Proceed Right,” or DAP Right, which will entitle them to an additional $3 per share if Sycamore is able to sell VillageMD, (They get 70% of the net proceeds of the sale, up to $3 per share).

I don’t think the merger agreement is public yet, but this from the press release caught my eye:

WBA shareholders will receive, at closing of the Sycamore transaction, one non-transferable DAP Right per WBA share.

Why non-transferable? After all, it would be more valuable to shareholders if they could sell their DAP right, and that way informed traders could price it based on the likelihood of it reaching the $3 max payout, etc etc.

After all, that’s how Bristol did this not long ago, when it acquired Celgene:

If the merger is completed, Celgene stockholders immediately prior to the completion of the merger will be entitled to receive $50.00 in cash, one share of Bristol-Myers Squibb common stock and one contingent value right (each, a “CVR”)

Sometimes I post for a naive audience, sometimes I want to get something out quickly and assume a more sophisticated audience, and with so much movement on SB 21 right now I’m opting for the latter.

So, first – the CLC offered some proposed changes to the law, which you can see here. (Mike Levin and I had just recorded a Shareholder Primacy podcast about the original flavor SB 21; that will still drop tomorrow morning; you can be the judge whether the overall assessment remains good in light of the proposed amendments). Brian Quinn says all that needs to be said about the CLC’s concept of retroactivity; I’ll just highlight what I think is significant.

Under the original version of the law, if the transaction did not involve a controlling shareholder, board level cleansing was achievable even if the board was majority-conflicted. As long as the disinterested directors voted in favor of the deal, it was cleansed – meaning, a board 4-1 conflicted could still cleanse the deal, so long as that single director voted in favor. If the transaction did involve a controlling shareholder, board-level cleansing required the creation of a majority-independent committee, but there was

Previously, I blogged about whether the proposed legislation is good or bad, including whether it’s good or bad for Delaware.

What I neglected to mention is that it is unequivocally bad for Delaware when normal people start to pay attention to Delaware’s fights.

Exhibit A:

But Delaware’s incorporation laws also provide some rights to shareholders. While shareholders have extremely limited ability to sue over the business judgment of corporate managers, corporations must prioritize them and treat them fairly.

So on Monday I threw up a rather inflammatory post about SB 21, which would dramatically rewrite Delaware law.  (Here’s a post by Eric Talley, Sarath Sanga and Gabriel V. Rauterberg, which takes a more measured tone).

As I’ve talked to people about the law, the first question I get asked is, “Is this a good thing or a bad thing?”  And that’s a really difficult question to answer, because “good” can have many meanings in this context.

Is this good for shareholders?

Well, I find it very difficult to take seriously the notion that the procedures written into the law will have any protective effect for shareholders.  The independence standards of the exchanges are notoriously weak; that’s why ISS and Glass Lewis frequently adopt their own definitions of independence, so much so that the Business Roundtable accused them of proxy fraud. The cleansing standards would insulate transactions by a board that is entirely captured by a counterparty, so long as a single member of that board is independent and votes with the others (a standard that one can easily see being transferred to the demand excusal context).  The definition of controlling shareholder would exclude people

I suppose it’s gratifying that the proposed changes to Delaware law support the thesis of my new paper, The Legitimation of Shareholder Primacy.  There, I argue, among other things, that Delaware imposes procedural limitations on managerial behavior that function more as a performance to the general public, to grant corporations a social license to operate, than as real constraints.  So, of course, as soon as those limitations started to have even the tiniest bit of actual bite – and in an environment where the prospect of federal preemption is largely nil, and corporate power has reached the point where a social license to operate may no longer be necessary – managers threaten to depart the state, and Delaware proposes of package of statutory changes that undo certainly the last 10 years of Delaware jurisprudence, if not the last 50, in favor of a model of corporate self-policing.

The story actually begins last year, when, in response to the Moelis decision, Delaware rushed to amend its corporate code to add Section 122(18), permitting corporate-governance-by-contract.  At the time, I asked – quite seriously – what is the value of the corporate form

This is very much a debate that’s been

Lately, several media and news organizations have “settled” somewhat frivolous lawsuits filed by President Trump, raising suspicions in at least some minds that the settlements were a rather unsubtle form of bribery, intended to win Trump’s favor with respect to other aspects of their businesses.

I am not particularly knowledgeable about bribery laws but let us assume, for the moment, that if these settlements were, in fact, shams to funnel money to Trump in exchange for regulatory favors, that would be illegal under some law somewhere. And, given that Trump is, you know, president, I also assume that, to the extent those laws are federal, charges are unlikely to be pursued by federal authorities.

But Disney/ABC, and Meta – not X – are incorporated in Delaware. And Delaware makes it a breach of fiduciary duty for corporate managers to intentionally break the law. I’ve blogged about the doctrinal difficulties that Caremark creates for Delaware (and they’re discussed extensively in my new paper, The Legitimation of Shareholder Primacy, now forthcoming in the Journal of Corporation Law), but whatever the doctrine’s flaws, there remains the intriguing possibility that an enterprising shareholder might bring a lawsuit – or even